Welcome to the Epsom College Economics and Enterprise Society blog. This site contains the musings of the army of students and staff interested in all matters relating to our subjects.

Disclaimer: the views expressed on this site are those of the contributors and not of Epsom College.

Tuesday 24 February 2015

The dangers of deflation

The government's target for inflation is 2%. Today, prices are falling at a rate that is below the target everywhere. This even applies to countries growing at more than 2% such as America, Britain and Canada. Inflation in China is at 0.8% and Japan's 2.4% rate is predicted to fall as it slips back into deflation. Thailand is already there. In the 1980s, countries in the euro zone had a high rate of inflation. For example, in Italy, prices rose at an average rate of 11% while in Greece the rate was 20%. Currently, 15 out of its 19 members are in deflation and the highest inflation rate is in Austria at 1%. This might seem like a good thing because goods and services become more affordable to consumers. However, the world is seriously underestimating the consequences of deflation.

The reason why it is a problem is because aggregate prices are dipping in so many places at once. Deflation is affecting a wide range of goods other than food and energy as well as countries that cannot claim to be leading the charge towards the new economy. This appears to be a sign of entrenched weak demand. Besides that, consumers will put off spending hoping that prices will fall even more in the future, further decreasing demand. Also, if prices fall but wages do not, it will increase the cost of production for firms and may lead to a decline or a stagnation in employment. Another risk is debt deflation. This means the value of debt will rise because the amount that is owed remains the same even if earnings fall. This is an especially big issue in the euro zone where many banks are already stuffed with dud loans.

The most severe danger is the fact that it is already here. Deflation makes it more difficult to loosen monetary policy. When inflation is at 4%, the central bank can take real interest rates below zero, to -4% by retaining headline rates at zero. But as inflation falls and turns negative, low real interest rates get harder and harder to achieve- just when you need them most. Most rich-world central banks have reduced their main policy rates close to zero to increase demand. The use of negative interest rates in a growing number of European economies to encourage spending will backfire as charging consumers to save in banks will eventually prompt them to use the mattress instead.

This means that policymakers have little room for manoeuvre when the next recession hits, which will happen in due course. It may be caused by China's slowdown in growth, or from the effect of a rising greenback on dollar-denominated corporate debt, or possibly from a random shock. In America, the Federal Reserve reduced interest rates by 3.9 percentage points on average in the six recessions since 1971. That move would not be possible today. The emergency measure of depreciating the currency drastically against a fast-growing trading partner would also not work because not many economies are growing rapidly and prices are falling, or close to it, in so many places.

Policymakers should take this problem more seriously and take bolder action to avoid deflation. Governments ought to increase spending on infrastructure to boost demand. The central banks should err on the side of looseness. Perhaps it is time to change the central banker's target for interest rates from the inflation rate to a goal for the level of nominal GDP. With this kind of target there would be no need to differentiate between good and bad price shocks. This would also send the message that policymakers are serious about getting rid of deflation.

On the other hand, central bankers change course slowly and they are exceptionally loyal to their inflation targets. Their conservative nature often serves them well. However in this case, it could cost the world economy dearly.




Sunday 8 February 2015

The problems with teaching economics

During the financial crisis in 2007-2008, many university students of economics found it difficult to understand what went wrong in the economy and how to fix it. There were brilliant researchers in the top universities who studied financial crises. However, despite this, their work did not get showcased in lectures. Instead, the undergraduate courses mainly focussed on the basic theory that has remained unchanged for decades. 

This had consequences. Aspiring economists were ill-prepared to analyse major economic issues such as quantitative easing, the credit crunch and bank bail-outs. This led to employers complaining that although their employees were able to deal with technical things, they had problems relating it to the real world. In particular, university graduates had weak knowledge of economic history, which was important in making sense of the financial crisis as it had parallels with the Great Depression in the 1930s.

Employers were not the only dissatisfied group. Students were unhappy as well. A London-based student-led group called Rethinking Economics was formed to challenge the conventional wisdom of the classroom. Manchester University experienced a backlash from its students, causing it to have lower student satisfaction scores and as a result, it placed lower on the league tables. 

The good news is that teachers are taking action to tackle this problem. A new curriculum has recently been introduced in University College London. This was the result of Professor Wendy Carlin's project. According to her, "The old textbooks had things the wrong way around. They taught concepts like supply and demand in an abstract way and then illustrated them with simple examples, such as the market for apples and oranges. By contrast, the new material challenges students to consider real-world topics from the outset."

However, although Ms. Carlin has challenged the mainstream teachings, the course still appears to be fairly typical. Rethinking Economics desires a curriculum that teaches the more unorthodox schools of thought. For instance, economic models normally depend on the equilibrium concept but the issue with that is that it does not happen in the real world therefore, it is a bad starting point. They believe that it is better to adopt philosophical discussions about the best approach to economics and sees Leeds, Greenwich and Kingston universities as models of how this can be achieved.

There are two rather different questions that have been presented. The first one asks if university courses are able to educate students with the most important insights from academic research. The second one asks whether students should be more proactive and learn more outside the curriculum. The curriculum deviating radically from the norm will surely be considered an oddity but perhaps mainstream theory must catch up with its students.